Today we discuss the largest wholesale funding market in the world, the eurodollar market, and how its “normal” form of functioning has dramatically changed, causing all manner of problems in the global economy.

In last week’s post we discussed shadow banking at its finest: the eurodollar market. It was the precursor to this article and so if you’ve not read it then it’ll be useful to do so here before reading this article.

In that article I mentioned that the eurodollar financing market has never returned to the levels prior to the GFC. Let’s first retrace the steps to understand what exactly has happened since the central banks all “saved us” from annihilation. In doing so I hope to lay the foundation for my belief as to why it is that some 8 years on the world is still mired in lacklustre growth, rising inequality, and this prolonged recession, which never seems to want to go away.

Everyone senses that things have changed, they’re different, out of sync… wrong. But why?

Let’s dig in…

Killing Us Softly – Medicinal Cyanide

Central bank responses to the GFC were that the federal funds target was at the zero lower bound as the Fed attempted to provide stimulus through unsterilized purchases of Treasury and mortgage-backed securities (MBS), or what is popularly referred to as quantitative easing (QE).

fed-funds-rate

Between 2009 and 2014, the Fed threw three rounds of QE at the global economic wall praying that at least one would stick. And so, like trying to carve a pineapple with a plastic spoon, failing, and then attacking the pineapple with yet more plastic spoons, the Fed took something NOT working to be evidence that quantity and size is the problem rather than strategy. Genius.

The third round of QE was completed in October 2014 at which point the Fed’s balance sheet was $4.5 trillion — five times its pre-crisis size. Quite some price to pay, and for what?

fredgraph

The Fed weren’t alone in this. Our sake drinking friends were at it too, giving new meaning to the phrase “big in Japan”, as were the Europeans and Brits. All in all, quite simply unprecedented and extremely unorthodox coordinated central bank actions.

jpm1

All this intervention by central banks was designed to get the credit markets cranking again. Lower interest rates being the primary mechanism and central bank balance sheets bearing the burden.

Let me just say that for anyone who’s spent some time understanding how an economy functions, you’ll realise that shifting rates to negative is bat shit crazy. If you think about how the capitalist system operates, you realise that we need a complete overhaul of education systems in the developed world, if all it does is puke up the kind of intellect currently running central banks.

Case in point:

Ask any money manager what the risk free discount rate should be and they don’t have an answer for you. Risk managers, you know those guys managing your pension funds, the insurance portfolios, mutual funds, and quite frankly every asset manager on earth with just a fraction of a clue, has to use some rate in whatever model he’s constructed. Since it’s now so difficult to know what the “real” rate is, asset prices are wildly skewed as a consequence.

Central banks, in trying to stimulate the global economy, created an environment where increasingly the risk free rate approaches 0%. I’ve seen some models whereby the risk free rate used accelerates towards infinity, using linear progression (I’ve spoken about linear thinking in a dynamic world before). Explain to me how that works because I can’t fathom it. In such a world or with such a theory risk disappears all together. Nirvana!

That’s a real consequence of central banks actions. Severe distortions in asset prices globally.

After QE

Although QE at the Fed has since ended, they announced the intention to maintain the balance sheet at its current level for the time being. In September 2014, the Fed announced a framework for normalizing monetary policy after QE, explaining that they would raise interest rates despite a large balance sheet.

The strategy was to mainly raise the rate of interest paid to banks on reserves and by engaging in reverse repurchase agreements (reverse repos). Quite a few money managers figured they were calling the markets’ bluff.

So we’re all familiar with the monetary policies but let me bring this back to the eurodollar market.

Signs That Things Aren’t Working

Some of the most notable signs that the interbank lending market, of which eurodollars plays the most significant part, isn’t functioning correctly is seen in the repo market.

Now think of all the government securities issued. Well, these securities can act as collateral much like your house can act as collateral for a mortgage. A repo is short for a repurchase agreement and they’re used for short term borrowing.

So a dealer or any holder of a government security such as T-bills sells them to a lender and agrees to repurchase them at an agreed price at a future date. In this respect it’s a simple forward rate agreement.  They are therefore really attractive for 2 main reasons:

  1. They’re very short dated (overnight or up to 30 days or more), and
  2. They’re government backed.

As a result they’re considered virtually risk free and typically super liquid.

The problem, and this was highlighted to me by Jeff Snider at Alhambra Investment Partners (BTW, Jeff’s work is excellent) is that we’ve had repeated repo fails since 2014.

Essentially what we have is the market refusing securities as collateral. Hmmm…

Now, as a quick aside. Other collateral enters the system as reverse repos.

So for example, if you want to enter the market but don’t have treasuries to provide as collateral, you can go into the secondary market and purchase those Treasuries using, say, junk bonds. You post your junk bonds as collateral, receive the Treasuries, and then use those Treasuries as collateral in the repo market. This naturally involves a higher spread cost but that’s essentially how it works.

Now when any of the underlying collateral fails as happened in 2007 and 2008 when mortgage bonds were rejected as collateral the knock on effect is felt in the repo market and liquidity dries up in a hurry.

Generally speaking in any crisis it’s reasonable to expect particular assets to be rejected as collateral as those assets are being repriced by the market. After all, if you’re unsure of what the price of any asset used as collateral is going to be tomorrow morning, then you’re a few sandwiches short of a picnic if you enter into any agreement to repurchase the asset again without figuring out how much risk you’re taking on the ultimate market price of the asset.

Now, to be clear there are two reasons that the repo market can fail:

  1. Credit risk
  2. Liquidity risk

Credit risk would be a sign that the collateral is not of high enough quality. And liquidity risk would be a sign of a dollar funding shortage.

I believe that a combination of the two are at play. Government securities are still considered high quality collateral but other markets clearly are not. Junk bonds, mortgage backed securities, corporate paper, and so forth are in question.

So we’ve had repeated repo fails. This means that funding as it should function isn’t taking place which is contractionary despite all the easing central banks have

1, 2  - View Full Page